522. Is Google Getting Worse?

Episode Summary

Title: Is Google Getting Worse? - Google search was revolutionary when it launched, providing the most useful results at the top. But some argue the quality has declined as Google's ad business grew. - Google makes most of its revenue from ads on search results pages. This could create "mixed motives" between serving users and advertisers. - Research suggests plumbers and locksmiths who advertise prominently on Google provide lower quality services, trying to attract one-time customers. - Google has over 90% global search market share, which reduces incentive to innovate. New search engines like Niva are trying subscriptions instead of ads. - Google supplements search results with featured snippets, which some see as lower quality than original sources. Google says this helps users find information quickly. - Long-time Google users complain search feels more commercialized, with more ads and e-commerce results. Google says number of ads is unchanged. - Monopolies can degrade quality without competition. But Google argues its scale allows it to organize information for billions of users. In summary, while Google search feels less ideal for some today, it continues working to balance usefulness, speed, and commercial intent. But lack of competition may reduce pressure to improve.

Episode Show Notes

It used to feel like magic. Now it can feel like a set of cheap tricks. Is the problem with Google — or with us?

Episode Transcript

SPEAKER_11: Freakonomics Radio is sponsored by Twizzlers. No matter the situation, Twizzlers is the perfect candy to relieve your boredom. And in a world where other candy is just too sweet and overpowering, Twizzlers is the perfect level of sweet and comes in the perfect chewy twist. Twizzlers are an enjoyable relief from the monotony of everyday life, and they taste great too. Head to the store and enjoy Twizzlers today. SPEAKER_09: Yeah! When Carl's Jr. plays with fire in the big Char-Brawled Angus Burger with melted pepper jack cheese, spicy Santa Fe sauce, and a whole fire-roasted charred Anaheim chili, you get layer after layer after layer of the big, bold, smoky sweet heat of the new Carl's Jr. Big Char Chili Burger. Available for a limited time at participating restaurants. SPEAKER_11: Do you remember when using Google to search for something online felt like magic? SPEAKER_13: I'm old enough to remember before Google, and it was really hard to find anything on the internet. SPEAKER_11: That is Ryan McDevitt. He is an economist at Duke. Google was a revelation SPEAKER_13: because it made this information accessible, and it was so useful. SPEAKER_11: The power of that revelation faded, as revelations do, and we all began to take Google for granted. When you needed some information, you just typed a few words into the search box. Very quickly, you got the answer you were looking for, usually from an authoritative source. But today, to me at least, it doesn't feel the same. My search results just don't seem as useful. I feel like I'm seeing more ads, more links that might as well be ads, more links to spammy web pages. Do you also feel like Google isn't what it used to be? Today on Freakonomics Radio, how did Google come to dominate web search in the first place? SPEAKER_04: People would be like, your search engine is so good, and you're not making any money, and we just wanted to pay you. SPEAKER_11: What happened when Google essentially became a monopoly? The problem with monopoly power SPEAKER_03: is that you can degrade the experience because you've locked in that user. SPEAKER_11: And we will hear Google's defense, or is it more of a threat? SPEAKER_05: If I took Google away, he would go nuts. Is Google getting worse, or is it just that, SPEAKER_11: as Milton Friedman might have said, there's no such thing as a free search? This is Freakonomics Radio, SPEAKER_08: the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything, with your host, Stephen Dubner. SPEAKER_11: In the beginning, computer scientists created the World Wide Web, and the web was without form and void. Darkness was upon the face of the internet. And someone said, let there be search, and behold, there was search, and in time, the search engine. SPEAKER_04: There was AltaVista, there was one called All the Web, or FAST, that was working out of Norway. There was one called Dogpile that was actually a meta search and hit many of the other searches. SPEAKER_11: That's Marissa Meyer. She runs a tech startup called Sunshine. Before that, she was CEO of Yahoo, and before that, she worked at Google for 13 years. She was the 20th employee at Google and their first female engineer. She joined right after getting her master's degree from Stanford in computer science. SPEAKER_04: I was very attached to a search engine called InfoSeq. I just felt like it had really helped me on my papers. And so when I even started working at Google, for about the first month, I would do every search on both. It took me a while to convince myself I wasn't gonna miss out on anything by not doing the search on InfoSeq. SPEAKER_11: InfoSeq and other search engines were okay at crawling the web and finding pages that contained the words you searched for, but they weren't great at figuring out which of those pages you'd actually wanna see. A search query produced a long list of sites in seemingly random order, and you would have to page through hundreds or thousands of links to find what you needed. Sergey Brin and Larry Page thought they could do better. In 1996, when they were grad students at Stanford, they created a search engine built upon a clever algorithm called PageRank, as in Larry Page, but also as in ranking your search results by page. Theoretically, the most useful result would be at the top of the first page of results. Think about a newspaper, if you can remember back that far. The important stories of the day were on the front page, A1. The less important stuff was tucked inside. That's what PageRank was going for, and how did it do that? Brin and Page had applied an insight from the world of academic research, where the most important research papers are the ones that are most often cited in the bibliographies of other papers. The web didn't have bibliographic citations, but it did have links. So when PageRank looked at a given webpage, it would see how many other pages linked to it. The most important pages, they theorized, would have lots of links pointing to them from other pages, and then the algorithm looked at how important those pages were based on incoming links. Their mission, they said, was to organize the world's information and make it universally accessible and useful. SPEAKER_04: Even when I was deciding to go to Google, the refrain I heard most often from people who knew I was thinking about working there was, why does the world need another search engine? There's already a dozen or so that are good enough. And I think it was Larry and Sergey rejecting that premise, that good enough isn't good enough for search. You can be great, and the one that's great will make a marked difference is really what led to Google's success. SPEAKER_11: Brin and Page were not the only researchers who thought about ranking search results this way, but they did get their version to market first, and people really liked it. SPEAKER_04: Every now and then we would get fan mail that would have a check or cash in it. People would be like, your search engine is so good, and you're not making any money, and we just wanted to pay you. SPEAKER_11: So how would they make money? In 1999, some big venture capital firms invested $25 million in Google in a deal that valued the company at $75 million. They considered or attempted a variety of money-making strategies, licensing their search technology to other websites, selling a hardware product that would let companies search their own internal files. If you had read Brin and Page's original research paper about their search engine, you might have thought there was one source of revenue they wouldn't pursue, advertising. In a section of their paper called Advertising and Mixed Motives, they wrote, advertising income often provides an incentive to provide poor quality search results. So which revenue model did they pursue? Yes, it was the ads. SPEAKER_06: One of the things that Google really innovated early on and was really successful in was getting ads to scale on search engines. That is Tim Wong, SPEAKER_11: who used to work at Google on technology policy. Now he is a media researcher and the author of a book about digital advertising called Subprime Attention Crisis. SPEAKER_06: And what that basically meant is that Google as a search engine became a lot more profitable than a lot of its competitors. SPEAKER_11: And what made them so profitable? As it turns out, the mechanics of the Google ad tech system were just as innovative as their search engine. SPEAKER_06: The way the Google ad tech system works is that there is essentially a marketplace where people are bidding for the right to show me the search ad. SPEAKER_13: Google was one of the first to auction off the first few listings on the search results. Ryan McDebbit again. Their position auctions, they call them. That's how Google made all their billions of dollars. SPEAKER_06: Now, one of the innovations that Google has is that that auction is based not only on how much money you're offering, but also on a number of characteristics around the quality of the ad. And in some ways, this is kind of Google's genius that they were able to set up a market where people bid for the right to show ads, but then there's also an incentive for those ads to be ones that are not automatically annoying ads. So when you click the search button, SPEAKER_11: Google finds relevant ads and chooses which ones to display above the search results based on several factors, how much the advertiser bid, how relevant Google thinks the ad will be to the user's search, as well as what Google calls context and expected impact. Google says that 80% of searches result in no ads being shown along with the results, but how important is that 20% to Google's bottom line? SPEAKER_06: It's huge. About 81% of Google's revenue comes from advertising on its properties and in search, which is really remarkable if you think about it, right? It still remains their core driver of revenue despite all the other things Google has done in that time, the kinds of things that Google is known for, like artificial intelligence and self-driving cars and all this kind of stuff, they all pale in comparison to the continued dominance of ads as the thing that funds the company. SPEAKER_11: The company is actually called Alphabet these days. That's the conglomerate that includes Google and a bunch of other properties, including YouTube. But most people still call it Google. And considering the financial strength of Google itself, this makes sense. But mixing search and advertising, as Google founders Brin and Page had themselves argued, could create mixed motives. Think about what happens when you do a Google search. You are looking for the answer to a question. The advertiser, meanwhile, wants the user to see information that promotes the advertiser's interests. Those two motives might overlap, but they very well might not. Marissa Meyer says that in its early days, Google did consider a subscription model versus an ad sales model. SPEAKER_04: As we started to do a sort of thought experiment around how to monetize, we're like, should we just have people pay us to run this search service? You know, we looked at them, we were like, okay, $20 a year. That seems like a reasonable price point for that time. And then we were like, theoretically, what if we could make a penniest search? And by the way, search ads are sold by the thousands. They use MILA, even Roman numerals, CPMs. SPEAKER_11: CPM, meaning cost per thousand. SPEAKER_04: So we were like, a $10 CPM, a penny per page. And we were like, well, we think people are gonna start doing more search, not less. And as people start doing searches, let's assume they do 20 searches a day, five days a week. They take two weekends off. That's 100 searches a week, and there's 52 weeks in a year. So that's 5,200 searches, which means if we could do a $10 CPM, we could make $52. So then you're like, well, wait, that means with ads, we could probably make $52, where consumers are really putting a value on this that's closer to 20, right? So it's two and a half times as lucrative to do it as ads, as monetizing the consumer directly. And by the way, in Q4, in the retail quarter, in the run-up to Christmas, the CPM that Google sees in North America today, I would guess is well north of $100 CPM. So it's not a penny per page, it's a dime per page. So then you're saying, well, now it's the difference between like the user might pay us $20 or maybe because of inflation and time, maybe now they pay us $100 a year, but Google can make $500 a year on those same searchers with that same set of assumptions. SPEAKER_11: So in the end, it was not a hard decision. SPEAKER_04: It wasn't a hard decision. SPEAKER_11: But Meyer and others at Google were concerned that showing ads with search results would degrade the experience for users. So she helped design an experiment to see how true that might be. SPEAKER_04: We said, okay, 99% of users will get ads and we're gonna hold 1% not getting ads, just to make sure that if we start to see in various search health metrics, a degradation in how the searchers were feeling and using the search engine, we could pick up on it. SPEAKER_11: This was back in 2000. The experiment was put in place. 99% of Google users getting ads and a small group of users getting no ads at all. But then Google sort of forgot about the experiment. SPEAKER_04: I think it was 2008. One of my colleagues came to me and said, we have this issue, we have advertisers who call our customer support line and they're very upset because they pay for ads and then they get assigned into this experiment group called no ads at all. And they can't see their ads and verify that they're running. And I remember feeling like I turned kind of white at my desk as I heard this, because I said, do you mean that experiment that I coded in 2000 is still running? And they were like, apparently. But I was like, you know, before we turn that off, this is the longest running split AB experiment in the history of the internet. And it is on this fundamental question about our company and our business. So before we turn it off, let's analyze it. SPEAKER_11: And what did the analysis show? SPEAKER_04: What we saw was 3% more searches from people who had ads than didn't. So basically there was an appreciable difference over a long period of time that people actually liked Google search results more and did more searches when they had ads than when they didn't, which I thought was really validating. And then we turned the experiment off. SPEAKER_11: When you consider that users who got ads did more searching, you realize this was probably the most expensive experiment Google ever ran. Think of all that lost ad revenue. But there's a bigger question. Why would ads improve the search experience? SPEAKER_04: Because you often get a higher quality result experience from someone who's willing to pay for it. I will say now as an entrepreneur, there's a point when you're building an app that you're like, I'm willing to put an ad out for our app. I think it's that good. Up until then, when you're in beta, you're like, we're still ironing out some kinks. I'm not sure it's worth to pay to put our app in front of someone. And that said, there are some queries that just have remarkably commercial intent. At the time, I was like, Madonna tour tickets. If you did Madonna tour tickets and you looked at the organic results, they were terrible. There's no tickets to buy. But if you put search ads there, the people who actually have tickets to Madonna's tour are happy to pay a lot to get those expensive tickets in front of users. And they actually make the search quality better. SPEAKER_11: That's an interesting argument. And I don't disbelieve the data Marissa Meyer is citing, but you could imagine a different story about ads and search. If you were looking for something specific and hard to find, like Madonna concert tickets, an ad might be the best search result available. But what if you just need someone to unclog your toilet? In the old days, you might open the big fat phone book known as the Yellow Pages. I got a couple of them right in front of me. Ryan McDevitt again. SPEAKER_13: A dash AAA sewer and drains, AAA Scott's plumbing, just ridiculous names. SPEAKER_11: Why did all these plumbers have such ridiculous names? Well, in a format like the Yellow Pages, whose listings were alphabetical, those plumbers listings would appear at the top of the plumbing category. SPEAKER_13: They're trying to attract customers who have an urgent need. They don't have time to search. They probably don't use this very often. And so that's the one way to grab attention is to be at the front of the Yellow Pages. SPEAKER_11: McDevitt began studying plumbers when he was a graduate student. He was looking for a dissertation topic. He and his wife were house sitting for another couple when he suddenly got an idea. SPEAKER_13: And so I jumped on a bed in the middle of the night and they actually had a Yellow Pages. And so I looked and sure enough, they're in the plumbing category, a bunch of AAs, locksmith, a bunch of AAs. And then you start to think about the logic behind that. So I spent the better part of two years calling every plumber in Chicago. SPEAKER_11: And what was McDevitt hoping to learn? He wanted to know if there was any sort of relationship between the kind of plumber who would use a ridiculous name to get to the top of the Yellow Pages listing and the quality of the plumber. The paper he wound up writing is called A Business by Any Other Name. I thought it was a clever title SPEAKER_13: because I put A in quotation marks, but I guess that's kind of lame outside of economics. SPEAKER_11: It's okay, Ryan, your humor is safe with us. Anyway, McDevitt set out to compare plumber quality as measured by data he got from the Better Business Bureau and plumber name based on how they listed themselves in the Yellow Pages. What did he find? The plumbers with a lot of As in their names tended to be more expensive and lower quality than other plumbing firms. He also found that the low quality firms listed themselves under multiple names. SPEAKER_13: You'd call up AAA plumbers and say, hi, I'm Mike, what do you need? And then you go down to A Best Plumbers, hey, it's Mike, what do you need? And then you go down to the Best Plumber Chicago, hey, it's Mike. And those plumbers are the worst possible plumbers. They're really trying to manipulate the Yellow Page listings to get a lot of results. SPEAKER_11: The Yellow Pages still exist online, but that's not where most people go today when they need a plumber. They go to Google. And there, McDevitt argues, the same logic applies. Firms that do everything they can to grab a customer's attention are not competing on quality. Now you're blanketing Google with a bunch of listings SPEAKER_13: and you're blanketing Google Maps with a bunch of listings. You're trying to win the first ad slot on Google, just like you try to get the biggest ad in the Yellow Pages. All these behaviors are consistent with a story you're trying to attract uninformed consumers who aren't gonna search a lot. SPEAKER_11: So if I'm reading this correctly, your research showed that plumbing firms that advertise on Google have 13 times as many complaints as firms that don't. First of all, am I misreading that? 13 times is the actual magnitude? SPEAKER_13: That was the right number back in 2007, eight, when I was pulling the data. So it's a big difference. And again, the logic is the ones that are trying to attract these one-off customers who are searching quickly those are the ones that you can rip off. SPEAKER_11: I've seen other research on position auctions for Google advertising. This is from Susan Athey and Glen Allison, I believe, which says that position auctions actually make search more efficient and they sort firms from high to low quality. Do you agree with that? SPEAKER_13: You know, it's a theory paper. And the theory paper, a beautiful paper, it depends a lot on the assumptions and the setting. And so they did not have plumbers in mind when they wrote that paper. What's different in the setting of plumbers is the costs are very different. The profits are gonna be very different if you're not providing the service in a legitimate way. If you're a fly-by-night plumbing firm, those are the ones that are gonna be most profitable and get the most value from winning the auction. A few years ago, Google was in the news SPEAKER_11: for a locksmith scam. The shady call center would create fake listings for locksmiths across the country advertising very low prices. If you clicked one of their links, the call center would send out a poorly trained subcontractor who then demanded three or four times the listed price. Google eventually cracked down on these call centers by requiring special verification to advertise locksmith services. This kind of problem goes way beyond shady locksmiths and plumbers and beyond Google as well. SPEAKER_13: I've noticed pretty plainly over the past couple of years that anytime you try to search for anything on Amazon, it's really hard to find what you're looking for. The first dozen or so listings, it's mostly junk. SPEAKER_11: McDevitt, we should say, actually worked with Amazon for six months a few years ago. SPEAKER_13: Looking for a phone charger, AirPods, whatever it is, these sellers have found a way to manipulate their search algorithm. Amazon's making a lot of money from the ad placement now. They've taken a page out of Google's playbook. It's quite lucrative for them to auction off those slots, and it's not always with the customer's best interest in mind. So maybe these are just intrinsic properties SPEAKER_11: of the modern web, the spammy and junky landscape you have to slog through in order to glean the benefits. But Tim Wong, the former Googler, now a media researcher, Wong argues it did not have to be this way. SPEAKER_06: It was a dream in the early 2000s when we saw Wikipedia coming up, like, wow, maybe this is an alternative way to generate all sorts of things on the internet. Wikipedia launched in 2001. SPEAKER_11: Wikipedia is hardly perfect or definitive. It is, however, an example of a vast website that provides valuable information to a huge audience, and it doesn't accept advertising. It's a nonprofit, and it relies on volunteers to create and maintain content. But let's face it, Wikipedia is pretty much a one-off. It is not a model for how the web is won. The Google model, built on billions of dollars of ad revenue, that is the model that's winning. SPEAKER_06: I think what that has effectively ended up doing is sucking the air out of other experiments that could happen. There is basically a generation of investors in Silicon Valley where you pitch them on a tech idea and they say, well, wouldn't ads work better? We know ads already work, why don't you do ads? So if I right now were on the air to propose to you that we should start a subscription-only search engine, you'd say, that's ridiculous. People would never pay for that because they're so used to having a search engine for free. And I think that is also a factor of historical accident, that basically since advertising became so dominant so quickly so early, we have sort of set the norms of the market in ways that make it really difficult for alternative models to form. And so I think it's almost a failure of imagination to believe that things could not have turned out on the internet any other way. SPEAKER_11: Coming up after the break, is it ridiculous to launch a subscription-only search engine? I'm Stephen Dubner, this is Freakonomics Radio, we'll be right back. Freakonomics Radio is sponsored by Capital One. Capital One offers commercial solutions you can bank on. Now more than ever, your business faces specific challenges and unique opportunities. That's why Capital One offers a comprehensive suite of financial services, custom tailored to your short and long-term goals. Backed by the expertise, strategy and resources of a top 10 commercial bank, a dedicated team works with you to support your success and help achieve your goals. Explore the possibilities at capitalone.com slash commercial. Strong bonds lead to lasting relationships. At Vanguard, their active fixed income team knows that strong relationships can build strong bond funds. Vanguard's active bond funds are backed by a collaborative culture and expert team. Vanguard is designed to keep fees low, creating an easier path for their active managers to seize the right opportunities to outperform at the right time. Vanguard knows active bond funds that help stabilize portfolios and generate income, can give clients peace of mind, so they may focus on more important things like lasting relationships. At Vanguard, clients are more than just investors, they are owners. Vanguard strives to do what's best for its clients and their financial success. That's the value of ownership. Learn more at vanguard.com slash vanguardactive. Visit vanguard.com to obtain a fund prospectus or summary prospectus containing investment objectives, risks, charges, expenses and other information. Read and consider carefully before investing. All investing is subject to risk. Investments in bonds are subject to interest rate, credit and inflation risk. Fund shareholders own the funds that own Vanguard, Vanguard Marketing Corporation distributor. We first spoke with the economist Ryan McDevitt in 2021 for an episode about kidney dialysis. His research had found that the consolidation of the dialysis industry into just two big companies had led to worse outcomes. For dialysis patients. Here's the McDevitt quote that stuck with me from that episode. Bad things can happen when there's no competition. So I asked him if the lack of competition in online search could also lead to bad things. This is a very standard theoretical result where if you have almost absolute market power, SPEAKER_13: you're gonna increase prices and you're gonna reduce your quality to the extent that it maximizes your risk. You're gonna reduce your quality to the extent that it maximizes your profits. In healthcare, that's very bad for obvious reasons. In a tech setting like search, the implications are a little bit different. SPEAKER_11: As of today, Google handles about 90% of online global search activity. SPEAKER_13: What's wrong with that? Mostly you're gonna not have that same incentive to continue to innovate to offer the highest quality products because you don't have to, you're just a little bit less disciplined. And of course, they're hiring many PhDs and they're putting out new great products all the time, but that rate would be even faster if they're worried about losing all their customers to the competitor down the street. There are a few search competitors, SPEAKER_11: Bing in the US, Yandex in Russia, Baidu in China. But again, Google's global market share is 90%. So maybe the next competitor has to come from the inside. SPEAKER_07: I worked at Google for nearly 15 years, mostly on their ad systems. SPEAKER_11: That is Sridhar Ramaswamy. In 2018, when he finally left Google, he was Senior Vice President for Advertising and Commerce. SPEAKER_07: I would say towards the last four, five, six years, I had concerns about the ad model overall on the internet that Google had helped create. It turned everybody, even the people creating news, for example, into people that were chasing clicks, into people that were chasing attention. So the entire internet kind of became this wound up toy. Is it just me, Sridhar, SPEAKER_11: or has Google search just gotten terrible? Because I remember in the old days, when Google first came on, I could find whatever I wanted to research, whatever was out there. And it typically produced results that were really useful if you wanted to learn something about the search topic. These days, it seems that a Google search produces results that are useful if you want to buy something related to the search topic. That's my experience, at least. How accurate or inaccurate is that characterization? It's not an accurate characterization. SPEAKER_07: And there are many factors that go into where we are today. The first one is this monopoly position. By being a de facto monopoly, there is no motivation to trim the number of ads that need to be shown. On mobile, for example, there are three, often four ads. They can take up two entire screens. We tolerate that because we don't really have any choice. SPEAKER_11: Ramaswami is now trying to provide some choice. He's co-founder and CEO of a startup search engine called Niva. SPEAKER_07: We never show any ads. We don't show affiliate links either. We don't play games. We take the quality of our results very seriously. We put you firmly in charge of your search experience. And because of our business model, we are also actively privacy conscious. We even prevent other people from tracking what you do. So what is their business model? SPEAKER_11: If they're not using ads or affiliate links, how does Niva make money? You pay a small fee. SPEAKER_07: We have a premium model, so anyone can try the product without needing to sign up for a subscription. But in a nutshell, we are a private subscription search engine. SPEAKER_11: The premium version costs around $5 a month. So far, they have around half a million monthly users. SPEAKER_07: People try Niva because they like the business model. They like the clean results. In 2012, Google co-founder and then CEO Larry Page SPEAKER_11: argued that Google couldn't really be a monopoly because, in his words, it's easy for users to go elsewhere because our competition is only a click away. Ramaswamy says it's not quite so easy. First of all, you have to build a search engine from scratch. SPEAKER_07: Search is hard to build. I joke to people that there's a three-part formula for search. Part one, make a copy of the internet. Part two, figure out what is useful. And part three, whenever someone types in a query, give them the top 10 results, ideally within 500 milliseconds. SPEAKER_11: In addition to its own index of the web, Niva licenses some data from Bing and from review sites like Yelp and TripAdvisor, but that's only the beginning of the challenge. Ramaswamy says a lot of websites don't allow search engines other than Google and Bing to crawl and index their pages. SPEAKER_07: And so we've had to slowly and painfully work our way through a set of relationships with each of the major players, like Reddit or Medium, so that we can crawl their content and include them as part of our search results. SPEAKER_11: Okay, but once you've done all that site-by-site crawling and built a solid ad-free search engine, users will just come flocking, won't they? Maybe not. Think about how you access Google Search. Maybe you go to google.com and type your query into the white box. But these days, whether you're on a computer or a phone, there's a good chance you just type into the browser's location bar and then get routed directly to a Google results page. SPEAKER_07: Of course, Google Chrome is the browser with the largest market share. And they weave a really complicated web of relationship with anyone that makes phones so that Google is the default. And even when you get people to switch, Google will very aggressively try to get them to switch back. SPEAKER_11: Google's Chrome browser is easily the biggest browser in the world with around two-thirds of global market share. In second place, with just under 20% of the market, is the Apple browser, Safari, which runs on iPhones and iPads and MacBooks. Google pays Apple an estimated $15 billion a year to be the default search engine on Safari. And that's why if you type into your iPhone, Chinese food near me, or even why is Google search so bad, you will get results from Google, not Bing, not Niva. SPEAKER_03: And what's that designed to do? Well, it's designed to make sure that consumers don't have to make an explicit choice or that Apple doesn't have to think about providing other alternatives on a level playing field with Google. It's protection money, essentially. SPEAKER_11: That is Jeremy Stoppelman, CEO and co-founder of Yelp. Yelp is a huge crowdsourced review site where tens of millions of users rate restaurants, stores, even plumbers and locksmiths. Stoppelman came up with the idea in 2004 when he had a hard time finding a good doctor. SPEAKER_03: In 2005, we started to get traction, particularly in San Francisco, with random people finding our site and contributing local reviews that had never really been created. You could look up a dry cleaner and see what people in the neighborhood thought of that dry cleaner, and that was an incredibly novel concept. So it wasn't long before Google took note. SPEAKER_11: Early on, Google licensed Yelp's content. SPEAKER_03: Ultimately, that partnership was not long for this world because Google decided it really didn't want to just organize the world's information, at least when it came to local search, it felt like it needed to own that space. SPEAKER_11: Google then tried and failed to buy Yelp. And then Google began inviting users to post reviews of local businesses directly to Google. If you use Google Maps, you've seen these reviews. And how did Yelp feel about that? Here is Jeremy Stoppelman testifying before the Senate Judiciary Committee, accusing Google of unfairly prioritizing its own content and even stealing Yelp's content. SPEAKER_02: Allowing a search engine with monopoly market share to exploit and extend its dominance to hamper its entrepreneurial activity. SPEAKER_11: That was in 2011. Stoppelman still feels strongly about Google. SPEAKER_03: They felt like no rules applied and they could do whatever they want, which I think is a telltale sign of an abusive dominant monopoly. SPEAKER_11: Stoppelman, like some of us, is old enough to remember a different Google. SPEAKER_03: If you go back to the early days of Google, it was 10 blue links, minimal ads, and those links were intended to be the best content on the web that they could find. And they were known for crawling every nook and cranny of the web. And users loved it. That's what made them successful. The problem with monopoly power is that you can degrade the experience because you've locked in that user. So in the early days, you have to delight users, as Google did. You have to give them a product that is just way better. But once you've become wildly successful, you might not degrade the results everywhere, but there's certain areas you could cut some corners and dial some knobs and generate a heck of a lot more money. And at that point, you really become a tax collector. And that's what Google really is. They're a tax collector. SPEAKER_11: So if you're Jeremy Stoppelman, what would a truly competitive market for local search look like? SPEAKER_03: Get Google and these other big tech companies to stop putting their thumb on the scale for themselves. Don't self-preference. Pick objectively the best content or the best website, period. There are other websites out there. Yelp is not the only one. There's TripAdvisor. There's Angie's List, HomeAdvisor. Take your pick, ZocDoc. There's lots of different players that have consumer reviews, but Google makes sure that the prime real estate is dedicated to two things, ads and themselves. SPEAKER_11: Google is now facing several antitrust cases in the US alone, including one filed by the Department of Justice alleging that Google is, quote, "'crippling the competitive process, reducing consumer choice and stifling innovation.'" They've already been fined for antitrust violations in the EU and in India. And just recently, back in the US, Google agreed to pay nearly $400 million to settle claims from 40 states that Google kept collecting users' location data, valuable stuff if you want to serve local ads, even after users had opted out of being tracked. SPEAKER_03: I've been shocked at how fast the winds on this topic have shifted. When we began speaking out about Google, we got a lot of eye rolls, both from the industry as well as from regulators, frankly, and from the White House. The number one most frequent corporate guest in the Obama White House was Google, to give you some idea of where it was not so long ago. SPEAKER_11: Coming up after the break, it took a while, but we did finally get someone from Google to speak with us. SPEAKER_05: Yes, you may ask one question. SPEAKER_11: She's just kidding. We get to ask plenty of questions. I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio. We'll be right back. Freakonomics Radio is sponsored by Canva. If you need to design visuals for a brand, the online design platform Canva makes it easy. With Canva, you can keep your brand's fonts, colors, logos, and graphics right where you design presentations, websites, videos, and more. Create brand templates to give anyone on your team a design headstart. Drag and drop your logo into a website design or click to get your social post colors on brand. With just a few clicks, you can save time resizing social posts too with Canva magic resize. If you're a designer, Canva saves you time on repetitive design tasks. No design resource, just design it yourself. With Canva, you don't need to be a designer to design visuals that stand out and stay on brand. Start designing today at canva.com, the home for every brand. Unspoken past, Magnificent Jerk, the true story of a fake story about a real life. Magnificent Jerk is an Apple original podcast produced by Pineapple Street Studios, available on Apple podcasts. In early 2022, a Brooklyn man named Vitaly Borcher was arrested for running a fraudulent online store that sold eyeglasses. It was the third time he'd been arrested for pretty much the same thing. He would send customers faulty or counterfeit glasses, overcharge them, and then if they complained, he would harass or threaten them. Believe it or not, this was part of Borcher's business model. As he told the New York Times, a mistreated customer might register an online complaint, which would show up in Google's index with links to his site, which in turn would boost his ranking on Google and bring in even more customers. Google eventually announced it had changed its ranking algorithm to prevent this sort of behavior, but you can bet that plenty of other people are still finding ways to game the system. After a couple of decades with Google as the main gateway to online search, the web is constantly shape-shifting to fit inside Google's algorithms. SPEAKER_04: I do think the quality of the internet has taken a hit. SPEAKER_11: That again is Marissa Meyer, one of Google's first software engineers. SPEAKER_04: When I started at Google, there were about 30 million web pages. So crawling them all and indexing them all was relatively straightforward. It sounds like a lot, but it's small. Today, I think there was one point where Google had seen more than a trillion URLs. SPEAKER_11: So is that URL inflation what's responsible for worse search results? SPEAKER_04: When you see the quality of your search results go down, it's natural to blame Google and be like, why are they worse? To me, the more interesting and sophisticated thought is if you say, wait, but Google's just a window onto the web, the real question is, why is the web getting worse? SPEAKER_11: Okay, Marissa, so Google's just a window onto the web. Why is the web getting worse? SPEAKER_04: I think because there's a lot of economic incentive for misinformation, for clicks, for purchases. There's a lot more fraud on the web today than there was 20 years ago. And I think that the web has been able to grow and develop as quickly as it has because of less regulation and because it's so international. But we also take the flip side of that in a relatively unregulated space, there's going to be economic misincentives that can sometimes degrade quality. And that does put a lot of onus on the brokers who are searching that information to try and overcome that, and it's difficult. It kind of has to be more in my view of an ecosystem style reaction rather than just a simple correction from one actor. SPEAKER_11: One way Google has tried to fight the overall decline in quality is by supplementing its index of a trillion web pages by showing you some selected content rather than just showing you links. If you ask a simple question about cooking or the age of some politician or actor, or even what's the best podcast, you may see what Meyer calls an inline result or what Google calls a featured snippet. It's a bit of text that answers your question right there on the search results page with no need to click on a link. SPEAKER_04: I think that Google is more hesitant to send users out into the web. And to me, that points to a natural tension where they're saying, wait, we see that the web sometimes isn't a great experience for our searchers to continue on to. We're keeping them on our page. People might perceive that and say, well, they're keeping them on the page because that helps them make more money, gives them more control. But my sense is that recent uptick in the number of inline results is because they are concerned about some of the low quality experiences out on the web. I think that the problem is really hard. You might not like the way that Google is solving it at the moment, but given how the web is changing and evolving, I'm not sure that the old approach, if reapplied, would do as well as you'd like it to. SPEAKER_11: And here's one more problem to solve. What you want from Google and what I want from Google may be different. This is Liz Reed. SPEAKER_05: You come in and you might type a question, but actually what you meant by that question is actually very different than what someone else might mean. SPEAKER_11: Reed is vice president of search at Google. SPEAKER_05: So I joined Google in 2003 in the New York office actually, and started there as a software engineer out of college. SPEAKER_11: So we all know that the fortunes of Google and Alphabet were built on search, which creates this massive audience for advertising. Since you are running search now, do you fantasize about how Google search could be different slash better if it were not an ad supported service? Do you stay up thinking, oh man, if only we had gotten around to some kind of a premium paid version, just imagine what I could do with this sucker. SPEAKER_05: In all honesty, one of the things that I love about working on search is that Google's mission around universally accessible is something we take very seriously. And I think that's really one of the powers of the ads model, like a premium model would say, great, it's available for a small subset of the world. And I think that's one of the best parts about the internet is the addition of advertising really truly democratized access to information. If you think about things like a billion users use us a day, like that's a lot of people. SPEAKER_11: I'm surprised it's not more, what are the other 6 billion using? SPEAKER_05: It's more than a billion. And then also some of the 6 billion are three years old, but over a billion people are using it per day. That ability to provide information to the whole world to help empower them, to help them go about their daily life or to help them find a better job or build new skills. I think that's an amazing part of Google's mission. And the ad system really fundamentally is what supports that. SPEAKER_11: Look, I am not in a position to complain because A, I've used Google every day from the minute it was available. So thank you, first of all. Second of all, when it comes to ad supported, like this show survives, it exists because of advertising. So I'm familiar with the model. I think the model is a really good model and I think it makes all kinds of businesses viable. That said, when you think about the original paper from your founders, there's a famous line, advertising income often provides an incentive to provide poor quality search results. So how do you reconcile that early reckoning of what's optimal with what has become real? SPEAKER_05: Behind the scenes in search, we take great pride in not only trying to provide high quality results, but ensuring that they are not influenced by ads. So we have a very strong culture that says whether or not you're an advertiser does not allow you to change the results we show. You cannot pay us to change how you show. Those results are very pure. And we go to great lengths to ensure that that is the case. And so the quality of the search we provide is run separately from the ads to do that. Relevant ads are actually quite helpful to people and people often click on them. And if they don't click on them, they disappear. We don't get paid if people don't click on the results. It's not we just get paid for showing them. But fundamentally, what we can do with the search results isn't affected by the ads. We build out our search results separately. SPEAKER_11: So here's my recent-ish experience with Google, having used Google for a million years. But in the last year and a half or two, I felt more and more that, whereas in the old days, a Google search would typically produce results that were really useful to me if I wanted to learn something about the search topic. And these days, it feels to me that a Google search will more typically produce results that are useful if I want to buy something related to the search topic. And then I find myself going down further. And then yeah, I find what I'm after, but it feels like a different environment. That is one person's experience, and I've read a lot about other people who have related complaints about Google. So for those of us who are whining, like me, at the moment, is this our perception that's changed or is the reality changed? Are there more ads or ad-related or more sponsored-related or even Google-generated snippets and so on on the first page of a Google search result than there used to be? SPEAKER_05: So the number of ads we show on a page has been kept for several years, and that hasn't changed. I do think people sometimes come to buy as well as to research a topic. And we have done more to provide sort of non-ads-related information about products. I do think we're trying to continually ask the question, how do we help those who have the intent to buy, successfully buy, and those who don't have the intent to buy not buy, right? SPEAKER_11: Is there a secret word that I can type in that indicates that I'm not looking to buy, I'm looking to learn? SPEAKER_05: It's a great question. So there's not a magic word that we're like, aha, this is the magic word that filters it, but we'll think about this. But we are trying to think about how do we do that. And so sometimes people will use like ResearchEx, but I wouldn't promise that that's the secret word. I think that is something that we are actually continually exploring on. SPEAKER_11: Now, what about the other non-ad results I'm seeing? I think you call these snippets, correct? SPEAKER_05: We typically use the word snippet internally to refer to some additional context or reference from the page itself that helps you decide if the results you're about to click on is gonna be more relevant so we can save you a lot of time by not having you spend time going to a page you're not really interested in. SPEAKER_11: So for instance, I looked up the other day, I looked up Premier League standings, the English Soccer League, and the result I got, it pulls up a table that looks like it might be a summary from some Premier League affiliated site, but it turns out that it's a Google table. And when I click into it, I get a much larger version of that. And again, as I keep clicking around it, I just stay within this little island of Google-generated results that are no offense, not great. It's as if I was looking for the New York Times, the Wall Street Journal, and instead I get a pretty good high school newspaper. It's trying, but it's not the same thing. And it looks pretty real because it's got the Premier League lion wearing a crown there. But then when I click the feedback link, Google is asking me, what do you think? This is helpful, this isn't useful. But then the score is wrong or missing. And I think, wait a minute, I don't wanna be the one to have to tell you that the score is wrong or missing. I want you to tell me what the proper score is. So again, how is this a better search result for me, for the user, than something that's editorially curated versus algorithmically created? SPEAKER_05: Okay, so this unit is not algorithmically created. The data would be sourced from a high-quality provider. We go through a pretty extensive vetting process to ensure the overall accuracy of any place where sourcing the data is high quality, highly accurate. One of the things that is really important to us at Google is that we not only show relevant results, but that they're very reliable and very trustworthy. Now, our assumption is not that the data should be wrong, but users get very frustrated if we are wrong and they can't tell us. We all make mistakes, right? And sometimes our providers make mistakes. So if there's a mistake, great, then users can tell us and then they can help us improve our product. SPEAKER_11: So I get that and I appreciate that. I just don't understand why if I'm searching for something that seems prima facie a request to go to the source, essentially, why I would want to get a secondhand version of that. I don't see why it's in Google's interest to do that. SPEAKER_05: So in your statement, you said, my request is to get to the source. That is your intent, okay? With all due respect, it's a very good and well-founded intent. But you're saying I'm a weirdo. SPEAKER_05: No, no, no, I'm just saying not everyone is identical in this world, right? Some folks may wanna go and check on this like every day. I just wanna go check, what's happening? What changed, what changed, what changed? And they've got five seconds to go look at, right? And so when we think about really trying to help people with their information needs, we need to recognize that both people care about depth, but they also often care about speed. If you go back in time at Google, this was one of the things that Google prided itself on was that it was fast. But fast isn't just about how fast the server renders the page, right? Fast is about how quickly you can get the information that you seek out. Why would this be useful for Google to do? Because some subset of the people who are coming really just want to find out the answer at a glance. Other people really want to do more in-depth research. It is still the case that we send more and more traffic to the web every year, but we also give people multiple options so that they can get their tasks as easily as they can and really meet their need. SPEAKER_11: So here I am complaining about Google search, which is absurd because it's such a bounty for me and everybody. But not only that, I also use the other products that have been created because Google search is so profitable. Google Maps, for instance, which I know that you've worked on, this is a live Atlas in my pocket. It's unbelievable. So do you think the moral of the story is someone like me who's complaining that Google search doesn't seem quite as good as it used to for research purposes, should I just shut up and be grateful for everything you're giving me every day? SPEAKER_05: I think one of the great parts about working on a product like search is that users keep raising their expectations about what's possible. In the early days in Google, if you entered a very simple query and you didn't get the good results, then you thought you did a bad job entering the query. Now you can enter a super long complex query. And if Google doesn't get it immediately, you're like, Google is an idiot, okay? But that's great because that challenges us to do better and better. But the bar of what users are expecting raises. If you asked a query like, when does Starbucks open? We would show you nearby Starbucks and their hours of opening. You have to understand that it's not like Starbucks opens at the same time in every single branch. But if we didn't understand that, you'd be like, what are you doing, Google? Users expectations rise and that keeps us on our toes. And that's what honestly drives us. If you didn't complain, if none of you pushed us, we might not make better and better products. So I'd love the provocation to challenge us to make search better and better every year. We're in it to help you. SPEAKER_11: Do you ever find yourself frustrated by search results in your civilian life and then use that experience to tweak the algorithm or tweak the results? SPEAKER_05: Yes, I find my examples, we don't tweak it to fix my needs, to be very clear. I send complaints probably every two or three days. You might think that we all think it's perfect and it's not. One of the things I will continually push us to get better on is how do we help people with more complicated tasks and how do we help people with exploration? Google is both immensely useful if you wanna do something like buy a house and it's still really hard. Because it's actually not just about buying a house. You actually have to figure out, can you afford a mortgage? Where would you actually live? And then you buy a house and you're like, oh my gosh, nothing works. And you have to find a contractor and these things go on. And so if you think about that, if I took Google away, you would go nuts. But you still have to do a lot of hard work. And so how do we continually push to go and say, okay, well, if that's what you're trying to do, how do we make that as easy as possible? SPEAKER_11: As we noted earlier, there's no such thing as a free anything and Google is no exception. It's all about whether you find the trade-off acceptable. I went back to Ryan McDevitt, our Duke economist friend, asked what he makes of the Google trade-off overall. SPEAKER_13: I am very happy with that trade-off. I think we're getting the good end of that bargain. Clicking on a few bad links doesn't cost you a whole lot in the scheme of things, as long as you're then careful when you actually go to make the transaction. So a few junky links, I mean, it's not so bad. SPEAKER_11: What do you think of the Google ecosystem, this unbelievably vast network of products and services, software and ideas, most of it funded by the simple fact that billions of people use their search engine every day, whether they choose to or not. Is that trade-off acceptable to you? Do you even consider it a trade-off? I'd love to hear what you think about this episode or any other. Send us an email to radioatfreeeconomics.com. Coming up next time on the show. SPEAKER_12: He was so angry when the book came out, the sound coming out of the phone, it was like this. Argh! It was like an ape in the jungle screaming and beating his chest. SPEAKER_11: Michael Lewis is considered one of the best nonfiction writers of our generation. So I thought on the 20th anniversary of one of his most influential books, it might be fun to revisit it. I didn't know it was the 20th anniversary until you called. SPEAKER_12: The book is Moneyball, the art of winning an unfair game. SPEAKER_11: It wasn't just that you were writing that the old guard was often wrong. You are impugning, not just their intelligence, but their virtue almost. No, I think it was more just the intelligence. That's next time on the show. Until then, take care of yourself. And if you can, someone else too. Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio. You can find our entire archive on any podcast app or at freakonomics.com, or you can also find transcripts and show notes. This episode was produced by Alina Cullman and Zach Lipinski. Our staff also includes Neil Carruth, Gabriel Roth, Greg Rippon, Ryan Kelly, Rebecca Lee Douglas, Julie Canfer, Morgan Levy, Catherine Moncure, Jasmine Klinger, Eleanor Osborn, Jeremy Johnston, Daria Clenert, Emma Terrell, Lyric Bowditch, and Elsa Hernandez. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by the Hitchhikers. All the other music was composed by Luis Guerra. As always, thanks for listening. SPEAKER_10: I found out that you give the best Halloween candy in all of Northern California. Is that true? SPEAKER_04: We give movie size. Word got out, and so now it's like thousands of boxes of movie candy every October. SPEAKER_08: The Freakonomics Radio Network, the hidden side of everything. SPEAKER_01: Every year. Amika. Empathy is our best policy. SPEAKER_00: When the weather app says rain, SPEAKER_08: the McDonald's app says McDelivery. Order McDelivery in the McDonald's app. I participate in McDonald's. Delivery prices might be higher than at restaurants. Delivery fees may apply.