584. How to Pave the Road to Hell

Episode Summary

In episode 584 of Freakonomics Radio, titled "How to Pave the Road to Hell," Stephen Dubner explores the theme of good intentions leading to unintended negative consequences in various professional settings. The episode begins with a discussion on the well-known phrase "the road to hell is paved with good intentions," highlighting its historical and cultural significance. Dubner then transitions into examining how this concept plays out in the realm of economics, particularly focusing on workplace policies and their unexpected impacts. The episode features interviews with several economists who have studied the effects of well-meaning policies that inadvertently caused harm. Josh Angrist, a Nobel Prize-winning economist from MIT, discusses his research on the Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA). He found that, contrary to its goal of helping disabled individuals secure employment, the ADA may have unintentionally reduced employment opportunities for this group due to employers' fears of incurring high accommodation costs. Further, the podcast delves into gender dynamics in the workplace, particularly in the context of the #MeToo movement. Marina Gertzberg, an assistant professor at the University of Melbourne, shares her research on the unintended consequences of the #MeToo movement in academic collaborations. She discovered that the movement led to a significant decrease in new research projects started by junior female academics due to reduced collaborations with male colleagues, potentially widening the gender gap in academia. Additionally, the episode discusses the complexities of pay transparency laws with Zoe Cullen from Harvard Business School. While these laws aim to eliminate salary disparities, Cullen's research suggests they might lead to overall lower wages as firms adjust their pay structures to avoid disparities that could lead to discontent among employees. Throughout the episode, Dubner and his guests discuss the importance of recognizing and understanding the trade-offs involved in policy-making. They emphasize that while intentions behind policies are often noble, the real-world implications can be complex and require careful consideration to avoid exacerbating the very issues they aim to solve. The discussions underscore the economist's role in analyzing these trade-offs and the ongoing need to refine policies to better serve their intended purposes.

Episode Show Notes

So you want to help people? That’s great — but beware the law of unintended consequences. Three stories from the modern workplace.

Episode Transcript

SPEAKER_07: Freeconomics Radio is sponsored by Capital One Bank.With no fees or minimums, banking with Capital One is the easiest decision in the history of decisions.Even easier than deciding to listen to another episode of your favorite podcast.And with no overdraft fees, is it even a decision?That's banking reimagined.What's in your wallet?Terms apply.See CapitalOne.com slash bank.Capital One N.A.Member FDIC. Freakonomics Radio is sponsored by Cars.com.Have you heard about the Your Garage feature on Cars.com?Here's how it works.You add your car to Your Garage to track its market value and cash in when the time is right to sell.Track both your car's historical and projected value.When it's time to sell, easily secure an instant offer from a local dealership or sell it yourself on Cars.com.Start tracking your car's value with Your Garage on Cars.com. Hey there, it's Stephen Dubner.Before we get to today's episode, I want to ask for your help for a special series we are just starting to make.It is about mentorship, and this is where you come in. We are looking for some good stories.It could be about a mentorship in business or academia or in sports.It could be a spiritual mentor or someone who helped you become a better parent or spouse.Or maybe you are the mentor. Or maybe you have a mentor who doesn't even know they are your mentor.No relationship is too small or too weird if it matters to you.Send us an email with some of the particulars.We are at radio at Freakonomics.com.We look forward to reading your stories and interviewing some of you for this series.Thanks in advance. And now today's episode. Here's a phrase you have probably heard before.The road to hell is paved with good intentions.The sentiment goes back at least to the Bible, but the way it's used today likely began with the 18th century writer Samuel Johnson.Since then, versions of the phrase have appeared in the works of Charlotte Bronte and Lord Byron, Soren Kierkegaard and Karl Marx, Ozzy Osbourne and Madonna. SPEAKER_06: Yeah, but how would an economist think about it?I would say economics is fundamentally about trade-offs, and there are always trade-offs.Today on Freakonomics Radio, three stories about good intentions gone bad in the workplace.If anything, it made them worse off by reducing their employment rates. SPEAKER_03: I find that junior female academics start fewer new projects. SPEAKER_07: But can economists help turn good intentions into good outcomes? SPEAKER_09: I can't emphasize enough that with slight adjustments, you can get your cake and eat it too. SPEAKER_07: Let's eat some cake. SPEAKER_04: This is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything with your host, Stephen Dubner. SPEAKER_07: When you look back, Josh, at the body of research that you've done, some of which brought you a Nobel Prize, congratulations.Thanks.How do you assess its importance or leverage in terms of influencing public policy?And really, what I really want to know is, is that a goal?I suspect you'll say not, but maybe if you're being 110% honest, you might say, well, a little bit sometimes. SPEAKER_06: Well, I like to influence public policy, and I'm happy when I influence public policy, but that is not what I get up in the morning and set out to do.I'm an academic, and what I set out to do is high-quality scholarship.I like to get things published in top journals.That's how I measure my influence.Now, ultimately, a lot of the work I do does affect public policy, or at least it becomes part of the discussion, and that's gratifying. This is Josh Angrist.And I'm a professor in the Department of Economics at MIT. SPEAKER_07: He did win a Nobel, along with David Card and Hito Imbens, for their, quote, methodological contributions to the analysis of causal relationships.That's a fancy way of saying that these three economists have found reliable ways to measure if a given factor—let's call it X— is the actual cause of a given outcome.Let's call it Y. Or does something other than X cause Y?Or does X perhaps cause Z, which may be the opposite of Y?If you are a policymaker hoping that X policy will cause Y, but it causes Z instead, then Well, good intentions, but not so good outcome.This gap between policy intention and policy outcome is something that Josh Angrist is particularly interested in.Consider U.S.tax policy. SPEAKER_06: We don't tax the rich at 100 percent, but sometimes we've been taxing poor people at 100 percent or even more because there's what's called a cliff effect. where when you cross a threshold, you lose an entire benefit.Well, the incentives there are very poor for employment.You don't want to change jobs and you don't want to move.So there's all of a sudden there's a lot of tradeoffs.Here's the thing. SPEAKER_07: Making good social policy is hard for a lot of reasons.First, it's difficult to know for sure what works, whether X will actually cause Y. Second, policymaking is part of politics, and politics is messy with all kinds of compromises to be made along the way.But perhaps the trickiest thing is that the people who are targeted by a given policy may react in a way the policymakers had not anticipated. in a way that may cause the policy to essentially backfire, at least to some degree.This has come to be known as the law of unintended consequences.It's not really a law, but it is a powerful and usually unwelcome force.Josh Angrist has been thinking about unintended consequences for pretty much his entire career. His first big research finding, along with the economist Daron Acemoglu, had to do with the ADA, or the Americans with Disabilities Act. SPEAKER_06: It was signed into law in 1990 by President George Bush I. The Americans with Disabilities Act expanded civil rights protection, meaning you could not fire or refuse to hire or pay less on the basis of a disability. SPEAKER_07: And what disabilities were included in the first version of the ADA? SPEAKER_06: Well, it's not concrete.You know, that was one of the things that had to get figured out.And there was a lot of litigation about what could be counted.It's tricky because maybe the employer doesn't know you're disabled.So there's always a lot of litigation in the U.S.when a new policy comes in, the courts kind of decide. And ultimately, the courts gave a fairly broad interpretation.So it covers a wide range of physical disabilities, including some that might not be obvious to an employer, like back pain.The other thing is, and this was relatively novel, the ADA requires employers to accommodate disabled workers.It's not clear what that means. The law says it has to be reasonable, right? So, for example, if you're a construction worker building skyscrapers and you're in a wheelchair, I don't have to accommodate that you can work on the 110th floor.But if you work at MIT, I do have to accommodate that you can get into your space and do your work.And here is how President Bush put it at the time. SPEAKER_05: With today's signing of the landmark Americans for Disabilities Act, every man, woman, and child with a disability can now pass through once closed doors into a bright new era of equality, independence, and freedom. SPEAKER_07: That sounds pretty great, doesn't it?At least from the employee side.It might make things more complicated and expensive from the employer's side.But hey, there are tradeoffs everywhere, right?For a society intent on providing good employment opportunities for everyone, the ADA seemed to say that it was worthwhile to ask employers to make these accommodations. Josh Angrist, meanwhile, he got to wondering, would there be some unintended consequences of this law with such obviously good intentions? So he went looking for some data, and he found it in what's called the Current Population Survey, which is administered every month by the Census Bureau. SPEAKER_06: That's where the unemployment rate comes from.You know, every month you hear the unemployment rate on the radio, that's coming from a survey of 60,000 households.And there's a bunch of questions there.Did you work?Were you looking for work? But there's actually a lot more there.There's employment, there's earnings, there's schooling.And as it turns out, there's a question about disability.Do you have a disability that limits work? SPEAKER_07: For people who answered that question, yes.Angrist wanted to know whether the ADA was helping.But he would need some kind of control variable, a way to compare workers affected by the new law with similar workers who weren't affected. Luckily, the ADA provided one.Companies with fewer than 25 employees were exempted from most of the law's provisions.This gave Angrist and Acemoglu a nice little natural experiment, as economists like to call it.So they measured, they sorted, they analyzed, and they wrote up their findings for the Journal of Political Economy, one of the top journals in their field. What was the headline result? SPEAKER_06: The surprising unintended consequence is that the ADA does not seem to have helped disabled workers.If anything, it made them worse off by reducing their employment rates and their annual earnings. SPEAKER_07: And can you explain why their employment would have been reduced?What's actually happening at a firm? SPEAKER_06: Well, employers, to the extent that they can tell who's disabled, they just don't want to get into it because they don't know what the costs of accommodation are going to be.The cost of accommodation could be very mild. It could just be a matter of letting somebody work on the ground floor, say.But they could be very high, and they're sort of unknown.Once you go down that road and you're in the business of accommodating, you potentially are on the hook for something big.Now, mostly that's not going to happen, but it is a problem. SPEAKER_07: Now, wait a minute.Wasn't part of the Americans with Disabilities Act a provision that a firm wouldn't discriminate against hiring a disabled worker?And therefore, by choosing not to hire a disabled worker because you didn't want to deal with the consequences, you are violating the ADA. SPEAKER_06: But it's much harder to make a case on the hiring front than on the discharge.How do you make a case that I'm not hiring?You don't have any data on who I interviewed and It's much harder to prove that, because I can always say, well, that guy wasn't qualified.We don't know if Josh Angrist was our first choice for this interview, for instance.Totally, probably not.So some workers, you might decide, even if you don't know they're disabled, you can kind of predict this person is going to be trouble, and they're going to sue me.And that becomes much easier once they're in the workplace.And the thing is, you don't have to win for this to be a problem.Mostly you won't win. It'll settle. But it's a hassle and it's a cost. SPEAKER_07: When I first read this paper years ago, it was one of those mind-blowing but obvious in retrospect findings.Like if you hadn't spelled it out, I wouldn't have thought of it on my own.But once you spell it out, you see, yes, that's the way humans behave. SPEAKER_06: Well, it wasn't obvious at the time, and it certainly was controversial.You must have upset some people?Yeah.Yeah, there were people that weren't happy, some disabled groups that were proud of the ADA.There were some economists that didn't accept the finding and went and did their own work on it.But, you know, the finding mostly held up in my view. We also did some cross-state analysis.Some states have more litigation than others.And we saw that that was a good predictor of where relative employment of disabled workers is going to fall. SPEAKER_07: The ADA has been amended since its original passage.It also had its scope narrowed by several Supreme Court cases, while some states have passed their own laws to protect workers with disabilities.That said, such workers are still far less likely to be employed than workers without a disability. Economists, meanwhile, continue to study which policies are best at actually helping workers with disabilities.That, after all, is the economist's job to analyze the costs along with the benefits. SPEAKER_09: I mean, my job is to just point out the tradeoffs. SPEAKER_07: That is Zoe Cullen.She, too, is an economist at the Harvard Business School.Her students are in training to create and manage organizations. SPEAKER_09: I like the study of organizations.I think that's where my topics, which would maybe traditionally be more on the labor end of economics, become managerially relevant. SPEAKER_07: For instance, how do firms and managers set salaries for their employees?Do all employees with the same job title and experience get paid the same?And how much do employees know about their colleagues' salaries? For employees, this is an important question if you're looking for a job or if you're hoping for a promotion. SPEAKER_09: You know, you find out that you're up for promotion and you're going to negotiate this new contract.And the first thing you wonder is, well, what are they willing to pay me?And if you could only just talk to the people who recently were promoted, recently negotiated their contracts, maybe you could hold out for a better deal. SPEAKER_07: Most firms are not very explicit about the salaries they pay.Sometimes they'll give a range.And there are sites like Glassdoor that compile data from former and current employees.But this kind of data isn't complete or even all that reliable.It's posted anonymously.It includes a lot of lower paid and often disgruntled employees.The data can also be outdated and fail to include total compensation like benefits. From the other direction, some companies have been found to solicit fake positive feedback on Glassdoor.So if you look at the whole picture, the available data around salaries is often imperfect information.Most of the theories put forth by labor economists, meanwhile, assume something closer to perfect information. SPEAKER_09: Yeah, so for example, if an employer has perfect information about market prices, they're going to indeed know everything they need to know about market prices to make their decision.When we introduce incomplete information, that's typically a model where we have to be more explicit about exactly what's outside the information set. So in the case of market wages, the employer might have private information about exactly what they think a candidate is worth and what they would be willing to pay.But they only have either a signal or know the distribution of pay that their competitors are drawing from. SPEAKER_07: An employer does have the obvious advantage of at least knowing what they pay all of their employees.Employees, meanwhile, have much less information.This gives the employer some real leverage, and some firms exploit that leverage when they can.It happened to Josh Angrist when he landed his current job at MIT. SPEAKER_06: I came to MIT as a full-time faculty member in 1996. I was happy as a clam to be at MIT, thinking I've really done well.And my former thesis advisor, Orly Aschefutter, who is a very famous labor economist, came to my office to chat.And Orly said, so what do you make?And I said, I make $85,000.I can't believe I make $85,000 a year.And he said, oh, my God.He said, you can't work for that. That's not what tenured labor economists make.If that gets out, that's going to be very bad. So you need to go and get a race.Orly was teaching at Princeton at this time?Yes, yeah.He's inciting you to riot against MIT, basically.Exactly.I didn't know what my peers make. As somebody has written, you're more likely to know about your colleagues' sex lives than their salary.And I now know, having served on some committees, that the variance within departments can be huge.So I was absolutely on the low end.So what'd you do? I went and I said, I'm going to leave.And I had to generate, you know, what academics have to do is generate offers.If you want to threaten to leave... It's like baseball.You have to say, I'm going to get myself traded to the Yankees.Could you get an offer from Princeton, for instance?For instance.And then you have to be, you know, it has to be credible.So you have to be prepared to take it if they, you know, don't pony up.So you did that? I did that.And eventually I got a raise.What'd you get a raise to? Well, I got a very large raise.I think I got up to around 150, which shows you how I was very underpaid.What cut of that raise did you give to Orly?I still owe him.The thing is, I owe Orly for so many things that wouldn't begin to pay it. SPEAKER_07: What does that say to you, the very fact that that gap exists between the 85 and the 150, and all you had to do was basically make it transparent?What does that tell you about the way firms operate?MIT is just another firm. SPEAKER_06: Well, some labor markets are more efficient than others.So we live in a labor market where, meaning professors, there's a lot of variance in pay, and there's also a lot of variance in productivity. We're much closer to people in the performing arts or sports.Every actor or entertainer, every MLB, NBA, NFL, you name it, they're all their own market, right?They all have their own package of attributes.And it is kind of hard to know what should they be paid. SPEAKER_07: So what would happen if firms decided to be more transparent about what all their employees were paid? Wouldn't that be a net benefit for employees?That's what I think people think.After the break, the law of unintended consequences strikes again.I'm Stephen Dubner.This is Freakonomics Radio.We'll be right back. SPEAKER_01: Old Dominion Freight Line was built on keeping promises.With an industry-leading on-time delivery record and low claims rate, we keep promises better than any other LTL freight carrier because we treat every shipment like it's our most important one.Visit odfl.com to learn more. SPEAKER_07: Freakonomics Radio is sponsored by Walmart Plus.Walmart Plus is the membership that helps you save on things you expect, plus the things you don't.The plus in Walmart Plus stands for all the ways you can save.Walmart Plus's suite of benefits can be used every day to help members save time and money.Members save on free delivery, free shipping, gas discounts, plus so much more.With Walmart Plus, members save on this plus so much more. Start a free 30-day trial at www.walmartplus.com. You may have noticed that there is a growing trend in what are called pay transparency laws, which require firms to give more complete information about what employees should expect to earn.A number of countries have passed such laws recently, and it's catching on in the U.S.too, in places including California and New York. The Harvard Business School economist Zoe Cullen has been studying the impact of these laws.What are the desired outcomes of such policies?And are those outcomes achieved? Are these policies fair?Cullen says that pay transparency policies come in three categories.The first establishes what she calls horizontal transparency. SPEAKER_09: It's just a simple way of saying I have a peer.What is the pay transparency between these two peers? SPEAKER_07: The second category is called cross firm transparency. SPEAKER_09: This is where the visibility is now between firms.So you'd be learning about what you'd get if you moved. SPEAKER_07: This is, let's say, the Yale School of Management comes after Zoe Cullen from Harvard Business School, correct?Correct.Has that happened, by the way, just for the record? SPEAKER_09: I'm not allowed to publicly talk about that, am I?It's not only transparency that a worker might have about different firm salaries, but it's also actually what a firm might perceive their competitors to be paying. SPEAKER_07: The third category is what Cullen calls vertical transparency. SPEAKER_09: Vertical is this understudied, very important midpoint.There are very few instances where public policy is really focused on vertical transparency.But this is happening to some extent by accident, which is finding out not just what your peers are earning, but what your senior management is earning, what you would earn if you were to go up the corporate ladder. SPEAKER_07: Why would you say public policy hasn't yet cared much about vertical?Because I would think, given all the conversation about pay inequality and income inequality over the past many years now, that that would be actually a focus even more than horizontal, perhaps. SPEAKER_09: My sense is that most of us think firms are taking care of this in the way that they are doing in the economic textbooks.In an economic textbook, you might say, well, the firm has to internalize the career incentives of the employee, and they should incentivize them to both stay with the firm and see that they are growing into bigger positions in order to keep them loyal to the firm.So the idea would be that it's the onus of the firm to essentially be very clear about the steep salary progression. SPEAKER_07: Do younger employees tend to talk about pay transparency and want to have more pay transparency than older workers? SPEAKER_09: Well, I've heard millennials do chat more about pay, but let me just say this.We also see a strong pattern of secrecy as you become richer, and age and wealth are highly collinear.Tom Nicholas and I, my colleague at HBS, looked at who withholds their information about income from the U.S.Census, and there the patterns seem pretty strong that it is about the money. SPEAKER_07: Now, you must have some psychologist friends put on your psychologist hat for a moment and try to explain why that would be. SPEAKER_09: The term that comes up most often when you just have an open text box for why don't you want to share this information is around fear of resentment.So that word resentment, I take quite seriously.You might also think there's some strategic element to this that is harder to articulate.So, you know, in the context of a workplace, you might have a sense that if it got out that you just got a big raise, perhaps other people would be vying for the same pie. SPEAKER_07: Vying for the same pie, meaning if your salary goes up, there may not be as much pie left for me.So what happens once salaries are made public?That's the question Cullen set out to answer.She recently published a paper that surveyed all the relevant research on pay transparency policies, including her own research. This was for the Journal of Economic Perspectives.Most economics journals want their contributors to describe the research but remain agnostic about policy recommendations.But the JEP is different. SPEAKER_09: They like us to take a stance.Hence the title, Is Pay Transparency Good?So less of a literature review and much more about where I stand on this topic. SPEAKER_07: And the implication there would seem to be that more information is good, full stop.Is that the case?That's what I think people think. SPEAKER_09: And you're here to tell us... Just that it's, you know, the typical economist, not so simple view. SPEAKER_07: Cullen's own research used data from a variety of sources.Some came from TaskRabbit, the online platform where gig workers submit public bids for different jobs.Some data came from ADP, the huge payroll company that manages worker paychecks and benefits across the country.She also relied on census data that tracked wages and employment histories for more than 5 million people.This allowed Cullen to compare workers in states that have pay transparency regulations with those that don't. Here's what she found.At companies in states that have pay transparency laws, wages became, as she puts it, linked together. SPEAKER_09: When one person negotiates for their salary, typically it will be in an environment that's highly private.Once you start to introduce transparency as a way of pinning the employer to pay people the same, suddenly one person's negotiation affects someone else's. SPEAKER_07: Okay, so that makes sense.When salary information is private, there might be a lot of variance.Once it's public, wages tend to converge.And that's exactly what these laws are trying to accomplish, to prevent firms from rewarding or punishing individual employees based on some kind of bias or favoritism.But that wasn't the only way these laws affected firms. SPEAKER_09: You can just see how it increases their incentives to bargain aggressively because if they save a dollar with one worker, they save that dollar with everybody.Ultimately, you start to see what I called compressed pay. SPEAKER_07: In one paper, Cullen finds that in states with transparency laws that protect workers' rights to discuss their compensation, there was overall a 2% decline in wages. SPEAKER_09: Essentially, the set of pay transparency policies that have been most popular are also having this unintended consequence of linking bargaining practices across workers and lowering average wages. SPEAKER_07: So does your finding, Zoe, that pay transparency can lead to overall lower pay, does it strike you as an unintended consequence of the policies?I don't think policymakers talked about that component of it.So that's a yes. SPEAKER_09: Yeah, I think I didn't know it myself and I found it very surprising. SPEAKER_07: Can you give us a sense of the impact of pay transparency on any observable pay gap between women and men?I assume that is a major goal of pay transparency. SPEAKER_09: I think it's pretty uniformly great at achieving this goal.In all these evaluations of countrywide policies, we've seen positive effects on gender gaps.Pay transparency leads to more equal pay. SPEAKER_07: Is it too reductive to say then that pay transparency is on average significantly better for women than men? SPEAKER_09: No, I think that it's a challenging statement to make in part because, well, I think the presumption that you have in the back of your mind is that women are at the lower end of the pay scale.And so this is a question of do the people at the bottom necessarily do better under pay transparency?When we talk about societal level transparency, I don't think it's clear. SPEAKER_07: So it sounds like you might consider this a sort of growing pain of pay equity.Would that be accurate? SPEAKER_09: Yes.And I can't emphasize enough that with slight adjustments to what these policies are doing, in fact, you can get pay growth and upward pressure on pay through transparencies.It's as though you can get your cake and eat it, too, with just thinking a little more broadly about the intended goal. SPEAKER_07: Can I have those slight adjustments, please? SPEAKER_09: Yes.Like, you know, don't focus.I say don't.I'm using the imperative with you. SPEAKER_07: That's OK.That means you're comfortable.I'm happy about that. SPEAKER_09: Okay.Thank you, Stephen.I think that's an invitation. SPEAKER_07: It is an invitation.I hereby formally invite you to use the imperative. SPEAKER_09: So don't focus so much on trying to get one employee to compare themselves to another employee.We want the comparisons to be one firm realizing that in order to compete for talent, they need to raise wages.Firms have to understand what the competing wages look like and employees have to figure out where to send those applications. The idea here is really important.You have a setting where employers don't typically have full information about market pay. but to higher paying firms within their occupation, when you start to increase what they know about the rest of the market, it's exactly the people who are being underpaid that are positively surprised. SPEAKER_07: There will likely be more pay transparency laws in the coming years.The Biden administration just announced it plans to require federal contractors to provide job applicants with expected salary ranges. I know there are quite a few Freakonomics Radio listeners in the White House.If you want to give Zoe Cullen a call to help design that policy, we'd happily pass on her number.I do wonder if she will use the imperative with you.Coming up after the break, one more instance of good intentions and an unintended consequence. SPEAKER_03: It's definitely a frustrating finding because it shouldn't be a tradeoff. SPEAKER_07: I'm Stephen Dubner.This is Freakonomics Radio.We'll be right back. Freeconomics Radio is sponsored by NetSuite.To reduce costs and headaches, smart businesses are graduating to NetSuite by Oracle.NetSuite is the number one cloud financial system bringing accounting, financial management, inventory, and HR into one platform and one source of truth.With NetSuite, you reduce IT costs because NetSuite lives in the cloud with no hardware required accessed from anywhere.You cut the cost of maintaining multiple systems because you've got one unified business management suite. And you are improving efficiency by bringing all your major business processes into one platform, slashing manual tasks and errors.Over 37,000 companies have already made the move. So do the math.See how you will profit with NetSuite.Now through April 15th, NetSuite is offering a one-of-a-kind flexible financing program.Head to netsuite.com slash freak right now.That's netsuite.com slash freak. Freakonomics Radio is sponsored by IKEA.Can you believe how expensive life is these days?Well, with IKEA, you can furnish your space beautifully and affordably.When you shop at IKEA, every dollar gives more.More quality, more sustainability, more inspiration. When these things come together, you can make the most of every day.Plus... Filling your bag can now be more affordable than ever because IKEA has hundreds of new lower prices on some of their most popular items.And don't worry, IKEA cuts costs without compromising quality.IKEA is making it more affordable than ever to furnish your entire home with home solutions you will love.Shop hundreds of new lower prices today at IKEA-USA.com.That's IKEA-USA.com. SPEAKER_02: Malcolm Glaubel here.This season on Revisionist History, I am diving into one of the weirdest and most infuriating corners in American life, guns.All the crazy myths we have about them, everything we get wrong.We're going to talk about TV westerns, about a crime in a little town in rural Alabama, about the nuttiness of the Supreme Court.It's our biggest series ever and one you won't want to miss.Listen to Revisionist History wherever you get podcasts. SPEAKER_07: Over the past few decades, a lot of policies have been designed to make workplaces more equitable for women.But as we've been hearing, not all policies achieve their desired result.Consider the research done by the economists Peter Blair and Ben Posmanek.They found that family leave policies, which give employees time off for childbirth and other family issues, have had the unintended consequence of increasing the average pay gap between men and women. Why?Because women are more likely to take advantage of these policies and men end up earning more on average.So as we've been hearing throughout this episode, good intentions do not guarantee good outcomes. Consider the recent work of Marina Gertzberg.She was born in Ukraine, grew up in Germany, got her PhD in the Netherlands, worked for a time in New York and now teaches in Australia. SPEAKER_03: I'm an assistant professor at the University of Melbourne in the finance department. SPEAKER_07: Before getting her PhD, Gertzberg had a variety of internships and jobs in a variety of industries.Banking, management consulting, the art industry... SPEAKER_03: I worked my whole life in industries that are male-dominated, and I have to say that I felt fairly comfortable as a woman.I didn't notice that much discrimination or anything like that. SPEAKER_07: More recently, Gertzberg got to wondering about discrimination in academia, specifically in academic research.She decided to focus on research collaborations.This is an especially important area for younger academics. SPEAKER_03: Working with a senior person, that has a lot of advantages.The senior person has a network.Promoting the paper is easier.Potentially the name of the senior academic also helps with conference submissions.Also in the publication process, the name of the senior person will help.Of course, the knowledge of the senior person is also very helpful.They usually have more experience with how to frame the paper.What is a convincing methodology?What is an interesting question? Collaborations are really important for productivity in academia. SPEAKER_07: But collaborations in academia are different from collaborations in many professional settings.In most places, a junior person is assigned to a senior person or gets attached to a project that a senior person is running. SPEAKER_03: Part of our profession is that our collaborations emerge organically.We decide ourselves who we work with. So if you don't want to work with a person, you just won't work on a project with them.No one can force you. What is also a really important aspect is that the lines between the professional and the personal oftentimes blur.So we create ideas outside of the office.We work outside of the office.We discuss ideas in informal settings, such as in cafes, over dinner.And these are contexts where ambiguous situations could arise. SPEAKER_07: Ambiguous situations like, is this collaboration purely professional, or is there perhaps a romantic or sexual component?Given the realities and history of the male-female dynamic, Gertzberg thought about cases in which a junior female academic collaborated with a senior male academic, and she started to put together a research project. Much like the Josh Angrist research we heard about earlier that had a fulcrum event, in that case, the passage of the ADA, the Americans with Disabilities Act, Gertzberg's research would also have a fulcrum, a before and an after.In this case, the before and after was the Me Too movement. SPEAKER_03: So people view the event date of the MeToo movement as October 15th, 2017, when Alyssa Milano tweeted that she was sexually harassed and encouraged other women to come forward as well. SPEAKER_07: The MeToo movement was meant to expose men who had sexually harassed women and to prevent future harassment.Those were the intended consequences. Gertzberg wondered if there might be an unintended consequence as well. SPEAKER_03: Because they are concerned they would be accused of sexual harassment.And yeah, this is the time when the idea was actually born. SPEAKER_07: The idea being a research paper, which she would eventually call the unintended consequences of Me Too.Evidence from research collaborations. SPEAKER_03: At the time, I also pitched it to a senior academic to just get a sense whether this was a good idea.The senior academic told me that I should rather not work on this at this stage in my career. SPEAKER_07: Why not? SPEAKER_03: Well, because potentially it would be too controversial. SPEAKER_07: Was this a male or female academic? SPEAKER_03: It was a male academic. SPEAKER_07: And yet you ignored this person's advice plainly? SPEAKER_03: No, I didn't ignore it.I didn't work on it for some time because that was during my PhD and I had other things on my plate as well.So I decided to not work on it. SPEAKER_07: But Gertzberg couldn't get the idea out of her head.Once she got settled into her first academic job in Australia, she put together a hypothesis. SPEAKER_03: The interesting thing about the MeToo movement is that its purpose is to increase protection for women from sexual harassment.So technically, women should feel very comfortable or more comfortable to work with men after the movement.On the other hand, there's a lot of anecdotal evidence and also survey evidence that men are concerned about sexual harassment accusations after the MeToo movement. So it is unclear what effect the movement would have on collaborations between women and men.So it is a two-sided hypothesis. SPEAKER_07: To test her hypothesis, Gertzberg began collecting data on junior female economists, women who had recently gotten their PhDs and were hired into university economics departments on a tenure track shortly before the apex of MeToo. There were not all that many women in her sample, fewer than 100.She gathered data on the research papers they were publishing and who they were collaborating with.She wanted to know what happened to collaborations between those junior female academics and their male colleagues and what she find. SPEAKER_03: I find that junior female academics start fewer new projects after MeToo, and that is mainly due to fewer collaborations with male co-authors.Before the MeToo movement, on average, junior women would start 1.6 new projects per year. And after the Me Too movement, women start on average 0.9 new projects per year.So the magnitude is 0.7 projects fewer after the Me Too movement, which is about 44%.Oh my goodness.And 60% of the decline are due to fewer collaborations with male co-authors. SPEAKER_07: I mean, that is a massive drop.How do you think about the size of the harm to the career of a junior female academic based on that number? SPEAKER_03: We already know that women have less output than men, and that partially explains worse career outcomes for women in academia, such as lower tenure rates.So having this productive output is crucial.And if that declines, that could widen the gender gap between women and men in academia. Of course, it is also important to then look at the outcomes, for example, tenure rates of women after Me Too or publication outcomes.And that is also something that I'm tracking.One challenge is that the publication process is very, very long.And for a lot of the projects that started after Me Too, there are no outcomes yet. SPEAKER_07: What can you tell us about the degree to which junior women sought out senior women to collaborate with? SPEAKER_03: After Me Too, women do not increase collaborations with any types of women. SPEAKER_07: And why do you think that is? SPEAKER_03: It could be, for example, that women may need more time to adjust and find new collaborators among women.It could also be the case that there's simply not enough women for women to substitute with.So if we think about the numbers, even among junior female academics, they're about 30% female.So even substituting with new junior women is fairly difficult with those numbers. SPEAKER_07: So you're saying that among senior female researchers, there's only like 16%? SPEAKER_03: Exactly. SPEAKER_07: So you're saying those 16% are probably oversubscribed with junior collaborators already, and there just isn't enough availability for junior women to make new collaborations with them, yes? SPEAKER_03: Yeah, that could be one explanation. SPEAKER_07: For what it's worth, Marina Gertzberg had no collaborators on her paper about this unintended consequence of the Me Too movement.It's worth noting that her sample size was small and her time frame relatively tight.So we should be cautious in giving her findings too much weight.But a group of researchers at the University of Cambridge seem to have corroborated Gertzberg's results using different methods. And if you go outside the academic world, you see a similar effect.A recent Pew poll shows that nearly 50% of men say it's harder for them to know how to interact with women at work.And here is how a headline from Bloomberg News put it.Wall Street rule for the Me Too era?Avoid women at all costs.Here's Marina Gertzberg again talking about her own research. SPEAKER_03: It's definitely a frustrating finding because it shouldn't be a trade-off.Women shouldn't have to choose between a safe workplace, not being sexually harassed, and their career outcomes, their productivity.On the other hand, I think my findings suggest that we can do something about that.As some time passes, there will be a new equilibrium and men and women know how to interact with each other. But it is also important to define what the expectations are for behavior so that men don't think, oh, I just have to say the right thing and I'm going to get fired.And so it justifies my behavior by not working with women. SPEAKER_07: And what kind of feedback has Gertzberg gotten since publishing these controversial findings? SPEAKER_03: I posted the first version of the paper in August 2022 on Twitter and I received a lot of reactions from Twitter.I believe this is also when Josh Angrist became aware of the paper and I received an email from him saying that the paper was interesting and that it would create a lot of controversy.That was really a high point of my career at the time. SPEAKER_07: And here, again, is Josh Angrist from MIT. SPEAKER_06: I mean, it has a little bit of an ADA-like flavor.So you tried to protect a group, in this case women, mostly young women.And maybe what you did is you made people think, you know, what's in this for me?I might just get in trouble.So better for me to stay away.So it's a lot like the employer who's worried about being sued by... you know, not accommodating or discharging a disabled worker and then having to deal with litigation. SPEAKER_07: I have to say, it's so fascinating to hear you talk about these constructs in a way that is, you know, quite rational and compelling and so on.It's also, however, Josh, if you don't mind me saying so, a little bit depressing because there are all these well-intended policies and people writing policies trying to help other people.And we find that not in anywhere near majority of cases, or at least I gather not, but in not a tiny fraction, there is a backfire effect of this unintended consequence. How does one as a right thinking human who wants the best for people and wants, you know, employers and employees to be happy and well compensated and so on, how do you think your way around the big issue of all these unintended consequences that promote worse outcomes instead of better outcomes? SPEAKER_06: Well, first and foremost, I want to draw your attention to the tradeoffs.Personally, I guess that's why I'm an economist.You know, I don't find the possibility of tradeoffs depressing.I find the possibility of tradeoffs interesting. That's what I study.You know, I recognize that it's not a perfect world and that policy design is always about tradeoffs. SPEAKER_07: Yeah, yeah. SPEAKER_06: And there's still things that are worth doing in spite of the tradeoffs.But I want you to look at that in a clear way and be aware of that. SPEAKER_07: Consider us aware.Thanks to Josh Angrist, Marina Gertzberg, and Zoe Cullen for their excellent teaching today.I learned a lot.I hope you did too.We will be back next week with a new episode of Freakonomics Radio.Until then, take care of yourself.And if you can, someone else too. Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio.You can find our entire archive on any podcast app, also at Freakonomics.com, where we publish transcripts and show notes.This episode was produced by Zach Lipinski. Our staff also includes Alina Kullman, Augusta Chapman, Eleanor Osborne, Elsa Hernandez, Gabriel Roth, Greg Rippin, Jasmine Klinger, Jeremy Johnston, Julie Canfor, Lyric Bowditch, Morgan Levy, Neil Carruth, Rebecca Lee Douglas, and Sarah Lilly. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by the Hitchhikers.Most of the other music was composed by Luis Guerra.As always, thank you for listening. SPEAKER_08: Okay, well, maybe you're going to shift my perspective on this.Don't tell my employer. SPEAKER_04: Stitcher. SPEAKER_00: Look around.You can find cars like these on AutoTrader.Like that car right in your tail.Or if you're tailgating right now, all those cars doubling as kitchens and living rooms are on AutoTrader too.Are you working out and listening to this ad at the same time?Well, multitasking pro, cars like the ones in the gym parking lot are for sale on AutoTrader.New cars, used cars, electric cars, maybe even flying cars.Okay, no flying cars, but as soon as they get invented, they'll be on AutoTrader.Just you wait.AutoTrader. Thank you.