The quest to save macroeconomics from itself

Episode Summary

Title: Quest to Save Macroeconomics from Itself Macroeconomics has historically struggled to provide definitive answers to big questions about the economy. Macroeconomists build models but often lack sufficient data to test them. Emi Nakamura is an empirical macroeconomist trying to improve the field. She focuses on hunting down new data to ground macroeconomics in facts. Nakamura's work has provided insights into how quickly prices change, the impact of government spending, the role of inflation expectations, and more. She has helped weigh in on debates using detailed price data. By finding new data sources like old microfilm records, Nakamura is slowly helping provide empirical evidence to address open macroeconomic questions. Her field of empirical macroeconomics is growing and aiming to incrementally improve the credibility of macroeconomics.

Episode Show Notes

When it comes to big questions about the economy, we're still kind of in the dark ages. Why do some economies grow so much faster than others? How long is the next recession going to last? How do we stop inflation without wrecking the rest of the economy? These questions are the domain of macroeconomics. But even some macroeconomists themselves admit: While we have many theories about how the economy works, we have very few satisfying answers.

Emi Nakamura wants to change all that. She's a superstar economist who is a pioneer in the field of "empirical macroeconomics." She finds clever ways of using data to untangle some of the oldest mysteries in macroeconomics, about the invisible hand, the consequences of government spending, and the inner workings of inflation.

Recently we called her up to ask her why the economy is so difficult to understand in first place, and how she's trying to find answers anyway. She gets into all of that, and how Jeff Goldblum shaped her career as an economist, in this episode.

This show was hosted by Jeff Guo and Nick Fountain. It was produced by Dave Blanchard with help from Sam Yellowhorse Kesler. It was engineered by Josephine Nyounai and fact checked by Sierra Juarez. Keith Romer edited the show. Alex Goldmark is our executive producer.

Help support Planet Money and get bonus episodes by subscribing to Planet Money+
in Apple Podcasts or at plus.npr.org/planetmoney.

Episode Transcript

SPEAKER_00: This message comes from NPR sponsor Bank of America with powerful digital solutions for local and global businesses so you can make every move matter. Visit bankofamerica.com slash banking for business. Bank of America in a copyright 2023. SPEAKER_04: This is Planet Money from NPR. SPEAKER_06: You know what really drives me up the wall? SPEAKER_05: Is it Jeff Guo Randhauer? We're doing this right here. All right. What drives you up the wall? SPEAKER_06: I really hate it when people talk trash about economics. You know, like, oh, economists, they don't know anything. They didn't even see the financial crisis coming. SPEAKER_05: But they didn't see the financial crisis coming, Jeff. So what's the rub? Okay, I know, I know. SPEAKER_06: But the economists that don't know anything, those are not all economists. Those are just the macro economists. They're the ones giving Econ a bad name. SPEAKER_05: Right. So as every Planet Money listener knows macro economists, they are in charge of studying all the big forces in the economy, inflation, unemployment growth. Whereas the micro economists, they think about how businesses and people make decisions out in the world. Right. And the micro economists, they know things. SPEAKER_06: Micro economists look at actual data, they're running experiments. They are legitimately trying to do science. Which means Jeff, your stance is that the macro economists are not trying to do SPEAKER_05: science. Macro economics is basically astrology, Nick. SPEAKER_06: Like, look at inflation. Macro economists still don't even know how it works. If it's mostly caused by real problems in the economy, or if it's like mostly a mind game, people like raising prices because they think everyone else is raising prices. Macro economists don't know. They're just out there making up theories, building their complicated models that famously don't work. SPEAKER_05: Jeff, I've heard your macro rant before. I'm sure I'll hear it again. We've all heard it at Planet Money. Why today of all days are you doing the macro rant? Because Nick, today I am turning over a new leaf. SPEAKER_06: I've been reading up on this newer branch of macro economics that's been making a lot of breakthroughs recently. It's called empirical macro economics. As opposed to fantasy macro economics. SPEAKER_05: Well, right. These empirical macro economists, they're doing the thing I've always wanted SPEAKER_06: macro economics to do. Instead of relying so much on theories, they're out there looking for clues, hunting down new kinds of data, actual data. And I truly believe that if anyone is going to get us real answers to these big questions about the economy, it's going to be them. Hello and welcome to Planet Money. I'm Jeff Guo. And I'm Nick Fountain. And Jeff, today we are going to turn the entire show over to SPEAKER_05: you because you're going to talk to one of these empirical macro economists, Emmy Nakamura. She's a professor at UC Berkeley. Yeah. Emmy is like this econ genius and she is trying to use actual data to settle SPEAKER_06: these long standing economics debates. Like, can government spending pull us out of a recession? What's the best way to fight an economy? Can government spending pull us out of a recession? What's the best way to fight inflation? And it's all part of her bigger project to solve one of the most important and frankly, most embarrassing problems in economics, which is how do we get macroeconomics to actually make sense today on the show? SPEAKER_05: Can Emmy Nakamura save macroeconomics or at least convince Jeff that it's not total nonsense? This message comes from NPR sponsor Mint Mobile. SPEAKER_03: From the gas pump to the grocery store, inflation is everywhere. So Mint Mobile is offering premium wireless starting at just $15 a month. To get your new phone plan for just $15, go to mintmobile.com slash switch. This message comes from NPR sponsor Honeywell, helping meet your sustainability goals with their consultative approach and technologies that are ready to help you get started. This message comes from NPR sponsor Crow. Don't avoid or resist the unknown. Face it head on. Crow offers top flight services in audit, tax advisory and consulting to help your business take on today's biggest challenges. Visit embrace volatility.com. If anybody's going to fix macroeconomics, they're going to be the ones that are going to be the ones that are going to be the ones that are going to be the ones that are going to be the ones that are SPEAKER_06: going to be the ones that are going to be the ones that are going to be the ones that are going to fix macroeconomics. Kind of makes sense that it would be someone like Emi Nakamura. Her grandfather was an econometrician. Both her parents are microeconomists, you know, the good guys, the economists that actually use data. So that seemed like a good place to start our interview. You were kind of raised in the world of economics, right? Like both your parents were economists. Your grandfather was an economist. Like what were dinner conversations like? SPEAKER_04: So it's funny because I don't remember a lot of conversations about economics per se, but I do remember sort of a general undertone of the importance of measurement and of data and of natural experiments and experiments more generally. So one movie that I've actually remember very well watching with my parents, it's an old movie with Jeff Goldblum called the race for the double helix. And it's about the helix. Yeah, it's about the process by which the double helix structure of DNA was discovered. And I remember there's a quote from the movie that my parents repeated to me, which was, there's nothing worse than a wrong fact. Nothing worse than a wrong fact, because then you're aiming your theories at the wrong end point. And you know, if you can correct the fact, then of course, you know, it might still be a long journey to the right theory, but at least you're not trying to fit something that isn't true. So that has been an idea that has really influenced me over time. And it's always been sort of a reflex for me to be very focused on measurement. And I think actually part of the way that I got interested in some of the microeconomic underpinnings and macroeconomic ideas is because it was such a reflex for me to think about like, well, if I see a measure like GDP or inflation, you know, how is that constructed? You know, where does it actually come from? How did it... What are the underlying facts? Exactly. SPEAKER_06: Exactly, because if we're going to spend all our time working on these kinds of SPEAKER_04: statistics, then we want to know where they come from and know that they're right. So... Make sure your telescope lenses are clean. SPEAKER_06: Exactly, exactly. SPEAKER_04: And then once you get started cleaning those telescope lenses, then you see a lot of things. But seeing things clearly, that's kind of been the big problem with macroeconomics. SPEAKER_06: Macroeconomics, it's all about these big questions like, why does some economies grow so much faster than others? How long is the next recession going to last? How do we stop inflation without wrecking the rest of the economy? And even some macroeconomists are saying we're still kind of in the dark ages when it comes to all that stuff. And so in the next part of our interview, I asked Emmy, why has progress been so slow? You know, every couple years you have this like famous macroeconomist who comes out and says, we don't know anything. We actually have no idea how inflation works. We know nothing. And I'm like, you guys have been working on this for like maybe centuries? Like, surely we have to know something. Why are people saying that we don't know anything? Okay, so first, I think the humble answer is to emphasize the fact that the SPEAKER_04: macroeconomic environment is changing pretty rapidly. So the current monetary environment really has only been around since the 1950s. So the world was on the gold standard for most of human, for a lot of human history. It was on other kinds of, there were stones, there were other kind of monetary systems. And monetary systems in history. But those are not the same as the system we have today. Right. And so one, I think, important answer to your question is that unlike physics, macroeconomics faces the challenge of a continually changing environment. Like the modern economic world was born like just a couple decades ago. SPEAKER_04: That's right. And so how many recessions do we have to analyze in the current environment? SPEAKER_06: I guess when I used to like, I don't know, roll my eyes at macro people, I guess I didn't realize how little data there was to work with. SPEAKER_04: Yeah, absolutely. So I would say traditionally, macro focused on looking at say GDP or inflation in every year, maybe in every quarter of the year. But still, if you're going to say that the modern macroeconomic era only started in, you know, 1980 or 1950, you realize that if you're going to try to think about questions like recessions or the effect of fiscal stimulus or of monetary tightening or something like this, often we only have a few major episodes to think about. So thankfully, events like the Great Depression or the financial crisis, they don't happen often. But that does mean that we are in a situation of trying to extrapolate from relatively small numbers of events. SPEAKER_06: Yeah, it's kind of like what you're describing. It's kind of like we have this ship called an economy and there are a bunch of like different dials and levers and knobs and things. And we haven't had it for that long. And we're trying to figure out which one does what. What do you press to make it go up? What do you press to make it go down? And sometimes the ship just kind of crashes into something and you're like, what? What was that? SPEAKER_04: Yep. Yep. I think that's right, because you're kind of you're potentially going into uncharted waters. And the longer you sail the ship, at least the same ship, if you're in the same ship, and that's the other issue that we're rebuilding the ship on a regular basis. But the longer you sail the ship, then the more you can kind of learn about the hazards that are out there. Right. But then if you decide to change the ship so it has like a deeper hull or something like that, now you start running into new kinds of rocks and so on that you didn't even know existed. So I think that is the analogy. SPEAKER_06: And that, according to Emmy, is the big challenge for macroeconomics. The economy is constantly changing and the data that's out there, it's just not good enough to make heads or tails of what's going on most of the time. So what are you supposed to do about all that? That is after the break. SPEAKER_03: Hi, this is Daniel Alarcon, host of NPR's Spanish language podcast Radio Ambulante. SPEAKER_01: Our new season features surprising stories from Latin America. In Mexico, a sculptor confounds archaeologists with brand new antiquities. In Costa Rica, gentrification sparks a war in defense of endangered turtles. In Colombia, a journalist's military I.D. is issued inexplicably with the photo of Cristiano Ronaldo. New stories every Tuesday, wherever you get your podcasts. SPEAKER_06: There's this very old idea in economics. You've all heard of it. It's called the invisible hand. And the idea is, you know, if something puts the markets out of whack, like if all of a sudden the wheat harvest fails or if someone invents a cheaper way to make clothing, the economy will eventually find its way back to equilibrium. The invisible hand will work its magic. And the way that works is through prices. The price of wheat will go up. The price of clothing will go down. And presto, supply will equal demand again. And in theory, the invisible hand means that economies are mostly self-correcting. They should just snap back to equilibrium. But in practice, that doesn't always happen right away. In fact, the question of how quickly or slowly this invisible hand works its magic is at the center of some of the biggest debates in macroeconomics. And for Emi Nakamura, that is the question she has spent a lot of her career trying to answer. So you've done a lot of work trying to understand how companies set prices. Why is that such a big deal? Yeah, that's a good question. SPEAKER_04: I think many people's reaction to that is why are we talking about the price of Cheerios? I really got into economics to think about something more important. But you have to recognize that this is the invisible hand that we think of as making markets work. What does that mean? It means that when you think about supply and demand and how does it happen that we have supply equating demand, the way it works is by the prices adjusting to make the supply increase and the demand increase. The demand fall. And if the prices aren't doing that perfectly, maybe if they're just off by a little bit, maybe this could lead to a very large difference from the ideal efficient outcome that we could imagine coming from a market economy. Yeah. SPEAKER_06: SPEAKER_06: And it's almost maybe another way to think about that is like if you think that the invisible hand is super nimble and the economy adjusts really quickly, prices adjust really quickly, then anything that happens, whether it's a shock, a pail storm, the government printing more money, the government spending more money, none of that really matters that much. That's exactly right. SPEAKER_04: Things are things are buffered by the price mechanism to a much greater extent. The invisible hand is going to fix everything for us. SPEAKER_06: That's right. SPEAKER_04: But once you get into a situation where the prices are not adjusting in such a nimble way, then there's potentially much more room for it to be important for the Fed, for example, to have the right policies. Because if it has the wrong policies, it's not all just going to be fixed by the invisible hand. And I think sometimes people forget how surprising it is that monetary policy does anything at all. The simple analogy that you can give is if you double the amount of money in the economy, but all the prices instantly double, then absolutely nothing happens. It's like saying, you know, if we measure your height in centimeters or inches, you're still going to be the same height. You know, no effect. What monetary policy is controlling is literally just the units. And so how do you get to a place where the units matter? And that's where you have to come back to price adjustment. Because in my little example of suppose you double the money supply and all prices double, then nothing happens. Well, this is an example where we think about completely flexible prices. Perfectly nimble, perfectly nimble, invisible hand. SPEAKER_06: Exactly. So studying prices in the context of macroeconomics is a lot about thinking about where we are SPEAKER_04: relative to this perfectly nimble, invisible hand. So all these debates about like, does the Fed matter? SPEAKER_06: Does the Fed setting interest rates? Does that even matter? Does the government spending money? Does that even matter? All of that, in a way, is a debate about do these prices adjust fast enough on their own or not? Exactly. SPEAKER_04: And that's where I think, again, we in macroeconomics and me personally, we're kind of triangulate from different forms of evidence. SPEAKER_06: I want to talk about your work, really looking to see how this invisible hand works. Because you went and got your own data, right? Well, so there was a group of researchers that had sort of started to use the price data SPEAKER_04: underlying the U.S. consumer price index because the government actually does go into stores all around the country and look at the prices on the shelves. That's how we know how much inflation there is. SPEAKER_06: Exactly. SPEAKER_04: That's how inflation is measured. And what hadn't been done was at the time, even actually people in the Bureau of Labor Statistics themselves weren't able to really do research with these data. It was a time when the data were kind of on some kind of big computer that was used to construct the inflation index, but it wasn't a data set that was very user friendly for doing other kinds of analysis. And so for my thesis, I spent quite a bit of time in like a windowless room at the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Wait, pay me a picture. Where was this? SPEAKER_06: The Bureau of Labor Statistics is a giant building and because it's such a giant building, SPEAKER_04: there are many rooms sort of in the bowels of the building with no windows. And the initial data set that we were using only went back to the 1980s. And so I kind of realized at some point from some of the older people who worked at the Bureau of Labor Statistics that there were these dusty old cabinets filled with microfilm cartridges of price from the 1970s. And in addition to that, these microfilm cartridges, they actually did not have a reader to read them anymore. There had been a reader, but the last reader that could read these microfilm cartridges had actually broken. SPEAKER_06: This sounds like the Da Vinci Code or something. So there's this like secret data set that only exists on microfilm. But it wasn't just microfilm. SPEAKER_04: It was this old kind of microfilm cartridge, which modern readers couldn't actually read. Oh my God. Wait, so how did... SPEAKER_06: So what happened? SPEAKER_04: Well, eventually we found this company that was willing to retrofit a modern, you know, cartridge reader to read these old cartridges. You had to build your own. It was definitely a labor of love. But in the end, the great thing about it is that we were successfully able to see the micro data. And the exciting thing, the reason that we were so excited about bringing these data back to 1970s is because that's when the last major inflationary episode was in the United States. So we spent quite a bit of time talking about the small number of data points. And so this is the big data point on inflation in the United States in the recent period. It's the late 1970s and the early 1980s. It's like you were literally like an archaeologist and you found this fossil from the last time SPEAKER_06: of the great inflation. Exactly. SPEAKER_04: Exactly. SPEAKER_06: And let me just give you some of EMI's greatest hits here. EMI has used detailed data to answer a lot of questions about how prices change in the economy. For instance, economists used to believe that with new technology and online shopping, you know, prices would start to change faster and faster. But EMI found the opposite. If anything, prices in recent decades may have been slower to adjust. And that has big macroeconomic implications, because if the invisible hand isn't all that nimble, then it's important for the government to step in to help bring things back to equilibrium. EMI has also found clever ways of using data to weigh in on a lot of other big debates in macroeconomics. She's found a way to prove that when the government spends money, it's not just moving that money from one pocket to another. Government spending can actually boost the economy. She's also used patterns in the data to point out new mysteries like why was inflation so low in the years leading up to the pandemic. EMI says that according to the data, people's expectations about inflation are actually way more important than we used to think. You know, I used to love to make fun of macroeconomics, but I got to say this research, it's pretty impressive stuff. Like we are legitimately starting to find answers to some of these big macro questions. And by the end of the interview, I kind of felt bad for being such a big hater. So I had to come clean. When I first heard about you, you had won like a bunch of really big prizes. Everyone was talking about all of these papers that you were coming out with. And people described you as an empirical macroeconomist. And that was the first time I'd ever heard that phrase. And I was like, that truly does sound like an oxymoron. I'm very excited about that phrase. SPEAKER_04: I'm seeing it more and more used by others as well. And you know, I think it's a field that they, to me, clearly should exist. You know, I think it's an exaggeration to say that there wasn't anybody in this field before, but I think it's growing. And I think that makes a lot of sense given the world that we live in, where there's an increasing amount of data and the fact that, you know, there's no question that we still need to make progress on these macroeconomic questions. SPEAKER_06: And credit where credit's due, because of empirical macroeconomists like Emmy, that progress, it is actually happening. Just slowly, one dusty microfilm cartridge at a time. This show was produced by Dave Blanchard with help from Sam Yellowhorse Kessler. Additional recording help from Jazz Williams. It was engineered by Josephine Nioni and fact checked by Sierra Juarez. Keith Romer edited the show. Alex Goldmark is our executive producer. I'm Jeff Guo. This is NPR. Thanks for listening. This message comes from NPR sponsor Allianz Travel Insurance. SPEAKER_00: The best kept secret in travel is annual travel insurance. One plan protects all your trips for 365 days so you can enjoy perfect peace of mind. Get a quote at AllianzTravelInsurance.com. SPEAKER_02: Support for this podcast and the following message come from Dignity Memorial. Celebrating each life with compassion and attention to detail that is second to none. They'll help you plan a life celebration now so your family doesn't have to later. For additional information, visit dignitymemorial.com